Public sector unions and the free-rider problem

Thumbnail Image
Date
2000-01-01
Authors
Turk, Alexander
Major Professor
Advisor
Peter F. Orazem
Committee Member
Journal Title
Journal ISSN
Volume Title
Publisher
Altmetrics
Authors
Research Projects
Organizational Units
Organizational Unit
Economics

The Department of Economic Science was founded in 1898 to teach economic theory as a truth of industrial life, and was very much concerned with applying economics to business and industry, particularly agriculture. Between 1910 and 1967 it showed the growing influence of other social studies, such as sociology, history, and political science. Today it encompasses the majors of Agricultural Business (preparing for agricultural finance and management), Business Economics, and Economics (for advanced studies in business or economics or for careers in financing, management, insurance, etc).

History
The Department of Economic Science was founded in 1898 under the Division of Industrial Science (later College of Liberal Arts and Sciences); it became co-directed by the Division of Agriculture in 1919. In 1910 it became the Department of Economics and Political Science. In 1913 it became the Department of Applied Economics and Social Science; in 1924 it became the Department of Economics, History, and Sociology; in 1931 it became the Department of Economics and Sociology. In 1967 it became the Department of Economics, and in 2007 it became co-directed by the Colleges of Agriculture and Life Sciences, Liberal Arts and Sciences, and Business.

Dates of Existence
1898–present

Historical Names

  • Department of Economic Science (1898–1910)
  • Department of Economics and Political Science (1910-1913)
  • Department of Applied Economics and Social Science (1913–1924)
  • Department of Economics, History and Sociology (1924–1931)
  • Department of Economics and Sociology (1931–1967)

Related Units

Journal Issue
Is Version Of
Versions
Series
Department
Economics
Abstract

A model of union membership is developed for State Government employees in Iowa. The union jointly produces a public and a private good using the resources from members. Employees have the choice to contribute to the union or to free-ride on the contributions of others;A probit model is used to model union membership. Membership is model as a function of wage gains, tenure, union dues and other individual characteristics;The empirical model is estimated using data on state government employees for 1980--1992. This data has very detailed wage information. The data also contains information on the dues required for union membership. Comparable worth pay plans were implemented in 1985. This provides a quasi-exogenous shock to relative wages that are not common in the public sector;A model of quits is also developed for the Iowa state employee. This model is used to develop statistical controls for potential section bias in the membership data. The model suggests that quits are negative to wages and to tenure during the early years of employment;Union membership is found to be wage elastic. In addition, membership appears to be more responsive to idiosyncratic wage gains than wage gains that accrue to all employees. The model was also used to estimate the impact that comparable worth wage increases had on membership. Union membership appears to be price inelastic when selection bias is not controlled for. Once you control for the potential bias, it appears that union membership is unitary elastic. This is consistent with an equilibrium where revenue to the union is maximized. It does not appear that other's contributions are close substitutes for own contributions. This suggests that union contributions are, for the most part, private goods.

Comments
Description
Keywords
Citation
Source
Subject Categories
Keywords
Copyright
Sat Jan 01 00:00:00 UTC 2000